Some notes and recommendations. To answer a recurring question: although I am happy for RRE's wonderful subscribers to send me potential items for the list, I absolutely do not want any commercial press releases. I am not opposed to commerce -- just the other day, after all, I passed along Hugh Beyer and Karen Holtzblatt's advertisement for their contextual design course. It has simply been my experience that commercial press releases are invariably useless. I mean really, they must be trying to make them that way, or else some useful content would sneak in occasionally. The truth, more likely, is that they are designed for a completely different purpose than circulation among a general audience on the Internet. Marc Rotenberg and I have just edited a book called Technology and Privacy: The New Landscape (MIT Press, 1997). It collects chapters by ten authors, each providing a new conceptual framework for understanding the interactions among technology, economics, and policy. One theme is the changing role of technology: social thought has always associated technology with social control and surveillance, but new technologies of privacy protection hold the promise of reversing that association, and the Internet is helping to create a new public sphere for debate and organizing around privacy issues. Another theme is the maturation of the traditional data protection model of privacy policy: this model originated in a sort of lawyer's folk theory of how computers work, back when computers were large, centralized, and unnetworked, but the world has changed since then. The data protection model isn't obsolete, but it has clearly come time to rethink the issues from the ground up. And what's what we've tried to do. It's a great book, it's cheap, and most of the online bookstores have it on sale. So check it out. I'll send an advertisement to RRE soon; in the meantime, you can read excerpts from the introduction by following the link from my home page: http://communication.ucsd.edu/pagre/agre.html In addition I've put some more of my papers online in the last few weeks, so maybe you'll find something of interest there. Mostly, though, I have a whole lot of recommendations to offer. The most interesting book I've read in years is Michael Allen Gillespie, Nihilism Before Nietzsche, Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1995. Building on the observation of Weber and others that much modern thought is secularized religion, Gillespie argues that an important tradition of philosophy is based on a view of God as thoroughly arbitrary and capricious. In the middle ages, the basic problem was how to reconcile reason and faith, and the basic solution was to derive both from the elaborate order that God Himself had instituted in the world. The serial upheavals of the Black Death, the Reformation, and the Thirty Years' War made that approach considerably less plausible, however. Philosophers accordingly began drawing much more on the previously marginal tradition of nominalism, which emphasized the tension between man's reason and God's radical freedom. This approach can be found in Descartes, who, Gillespie argues, founds a tradition in which man himself must take over many or all of God's functions. Gillespie then traces a downward slide through Fichte, the romantic movement, the Russian nihilists, Schopenhauer, and many others, finally down to Nietzsche. Although I doubt that Gillespie and I would agree about many things, I think that he is basically right about this. The basic pattern is widespread; in fact, you can see it clearly in AI research, which has long opposed the heroic and (in practice) almost futile rationality of the individual agent to an "uncertain, unpredictable, and changing environment". Gillespie is one conservative dude, a product of the followers of Leo Strauss at the University of Chicago. His political polemics sometimes get in the way, for example when he treats people's enemies as authorities on them, or when he goes whole-hog into guilt-by- association tactics in recounting the beliefs of the Russian nihilists that Turgenev wrote about. Nonetheless, I think that Gillespie's variety of conservatism will become more important in coming years. The conservative movement has much to gain by reactivating an awareness of the theological sources of modern social and philosophical thought, thereby shifting the whole of public intellectual discourse back onto religious terrain. This is why I keep saying that we're returning to the middle ages, and why I expect the institutional system of the United States to continue its rapid convergence with that of Iran. Also immensely recommended is David F. Noble, The Religion of Technology: The Divinity of Man and the Spirit of Invention, New York: Knopf, 1997. Although Noble's politics could not be any more different from Gillespie's, his thesis is remarkably parallel, to wit, that technology is, and always has been, primarily a religious enterprise. It has long been known that important technologists for a thousand years have also written religious works, but Noble is just about the first person to go and read them all, taking them seriously as an integral part of the technological tradition. Indeed, from the beginning of technology with the Benedictine monks down to the present day, one finds technologists suggesting with remarkable consistency that technology will cause man to resemble God. In some cases this suggestion is part of an overtly elaborated theology; in other cases the theological ideas have been translated into secular terms, but with religious language reappearing from time to time as if the author had discovered the analogy afresh. NASA, for example, is largely a religious organization, run by religious people for quite openly admitted religious purposes. Babbage and Wiener, likewise, were explicit about the religious nature of their work in computing, and (as I suggest in a column coming out in the November issue of Technology Review) the discourse of cyberspace is full of classical millenarian themes. For Noble, all of this is reason to reject technology. Of course, the word "technology" can mean a lot of different things, so that rejecting technology can amount to a wide variety of different positions. In other work, Noble vociferously resists those false friends who would water down the memory of the Luddites, making their attitude toward machinery seem fancier than it really was. My own view is that technology is capable of taking many different directions, and that technologies embody ideas, and that those ideas are frequently fouled up. Noble's objection to the religion of technology is that it is a religion; my objection is that it is a lousy religion. As with Gillespie's genealogy of nihilism, reactivating an awareness of the religious ideas and practices that became technology -- that is, recognizing which religion technology is -- shifts the debate about technology onto religious grounds. Gillespie wants to undermine poststructuralism and communism, Noble wants to undermine industrial automation, and they're both right. This is a serious situation. Does it mean that we should rewind society back to the middle ages? No, I don't think so. Does it mean that we probably will rewind society back to the middle ages? There I'm not so sure. Also highly recommended, though seemingly completely unrelated to theology: C. Edwin Baker, Giving the audience what it wants, Ohio State Law Journal 58(2), 1997, pages 311-417. We too often hear the catechism of the market applied uncritically to information. The problem is that information works quite differently from physical commodities such as sandwiches and trucks. Information, in short, is a public good. This is well-known, but nobody has catalogued all of its consequences. Ed Baker is a First Amendment scholar who couldn't care less about cyberspace. You may recall my recommendation of his book about the influence of advertisers on the news. He tells me that he wrote this paper because he simply needed a citation for various observations about the public good nature of information but couldn't find one. The result is an interminable catalog of the amazing economic pecularities of information. Unless you've gotten used to all of these facts, you're simply not in a position to talk about the economic issues (and therefore the policy issues) associated with information technology. While we're reading law reviews, here are a few more useful references: Mark A. Lemley, Antitrust and the Internet standardization problem, Connecticut Law Review 28, 1996, pages 1041-1094. This paper and the next are required reading now that the Justice Department has moved on Microsoft. Basically they explain why this is the probably best shot that Justice will ever have. James J. Anton and Dennis A. Yao, Standard-setting consortia, antitrust, and high-technology industries, Antitrust Law Journal 64, 1995, pages 247-265. Julie E. Cohen, A right to read anonymously: A closer look at "copyright management" in cyberspace, Connecticut Law Review 28, 1996, pages 981-1039. The title says it. One counterargument against information-as-public-good arguments like Ed Baker's is that information is excludable, meaning that an information vendor can use "copyright management" technologies to control who uses it and who doesn't. This would be great from the point of view of neoclassical economics, but it would be a catastrophe from the point of view of privacy if publishers could know just exactly what you read, and when. Marcel Kahan and Michael Klausner, Path dependence in corporate contracting: Increasing returns, herd behavior and cognitive biases, Washington University Law Quarterly 74, 1996, pages 347-366. Even though this paper doesn't seem like it's relevant to information technology on the surface, I include it because it's highly relevant to the idea that privacy can be treated as a good to be allocated by the market. The idea is that different companies can compete in the marketplace on their handling of personal information, and that the market would thereby reveal just how much privacy people really want, and exactly what they're willing to give up to get it. This is one more example of the mechanical application of market language to matters involving information, and as with all the other examples, serious analysis of the proposal doesn't begin until we take seriously the particularities of the market. If the market doesn't work right then it won't allocate goods in the right way. If we think about privacy markets as markets in contract terms -- privacy, after all, isn't a separate and discrete good, but rather a set of terms incorporated in the contract governing the sale of some other good or service -- then we need to understand the properties of markets in contract terms that relate to the handling of personal information. Kahan and Klausner suggest that markets in contract terms exhibit network effects, meaning that market participants benefit from using the same contract terms that others have used before them. That means that a firm that wishes to offer innovative contract terms will have to make a potentially substantial investment that other firms using more commonplace terms won't have to make. The result could be to restrict the diversity of terms that are available to consumers in the marketplace. Nobody has proven whether this really happens -- indeed, it is a characteristic of debate in this area that neither the proponents nor opponents of market mechanisms have the slightest empirical evidence one way or the other. But the argument is plausible enough that we shouldn't buy the privacy-market story without considerable investigation. I also recommend ACM's StandardView, a crudely produced but intellectually serious magazine about standards and standardization. I have long said that standards dynamics are the key to understanding the evolution of information infrastructure, and StandardView provides some concrete detail on the (often strange) standardization process. A tremendous number of books have been published in the last couple years on the subjects covered on RRE. No mortal could possibly review them all, but here at least is a partial list of them: Stephen A. Brown, Revolution at the Checkout Counter: The Explosion of the Bar Code, Harvard University Press, 1997. Thomas H. Davenport and Laurence Prusak, Information Ecology: Mastering the Information and Knowledge Environment, Oxford University Press, 1997. William Dutton, ed, Information and Communication Technologies: Visions and Realities, Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1996. Mike Featherstone and Roger Burrows, eds, Cyberspace/Cyberbodies/Cyberpunk: Cultures of Technological Embodiment, Sage, 1996. Ruth Garner and Mark G. Gillingham, Internet Communication in Six Classrooms: Conversations Across Time, Space, and Culture, Erlbaum, 1996. Laura J. Gurak, Persuasion and Privacy in Cyberspace: The Online Protests over Lotus Marketplace and the Clipper Chip, New Haven: Yale University Press, 1997. Richard Hawkins, Robin Mansell, and Jim Skea, eds, Standards, Innovation and Competitiveness: The Politics and Economics of Standards in Natural and Technical Environments, Edward Elgar, 1995. Marco Iansiti, Technology Integration: Making Critical Choices in a Dynamic World, Boston: Harvard Business School Press, 1997. Brian Kahin and Charles Nesson, eds, Borders in Cyberspace: Information Policy and the Global Information Infrastructure, Cambridge: MIT Press, 1997. Brian Kahin and James H. Keller, eds, Coordinating the Internet, Cambridge: MIT Press, 1997. Brian Kahin and Ernest Wilson, eds, National Information Infrastructure Initiatives, Cambridge: MIT Press, 1996. Ravi Kalakota and Andrew B. Whinston, Frontiers of Electronic Commerce, Addison-Wesley, 1996. Samuel Krislov, How Nations Choose Product Standards and Standards Change Nations, Pittsburgh: University of Pittsburgh Press, 1997. Donald M. Lamberton, ed, The Economics of Communication and Information, Cheltenham, UK: Elgar, 1996. Pierre Levy, Collective Intelligence: Mankind's Emerging World in Cyberspace, translated by Robert Bononno, Plenum Press, 1997. Jessica Lipnack and Jeffrey Stamps, Virtual Teams: Reaching Across Space, Time, and Organizations With Technology, Wiley, 1997. Brian D. Loader, ed, The Governance of Cyberspace: Politics, Technology and Global Restructuring, Routledge, 1997. Lee W. McKnight and Joseph P. Bailey, eds, Internet Economics, Cambridge: MIT Press, 1997. Alberto Melucci, Challenging Codes: Collective Action in the Information Age, Cambridge University Press, 1996. Marc H. Meyer and Alvin P. Lehnerd, The Power of Product Platforms: Building Value and Cost Leadership, Free Press, 1997. W. Russell Neuman, Lee McKnight and Richard Jay Soloman, The Gordian Knot: Political Gridlock on the Information Highway, Cambridge: MIT Press, 1997. Arthur L. Norberg and Judy E. O'Neill, Transforming Computer Technology: Information Processing for the Pentagon, 1962-1986, Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1996. Wanda Orlikowski et al, eds, Information Technology and Changes in Organizational Work, London: Chapman and Hall, 1996. David Porter, Internet Culture, Routledge, 1996. Gene I. Rochlin, Trapped in The Net: The Unanticipated Consequences of Computerization, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1997. Ziauddin Sardar and Jerome R. Ravetz, eds, Cyberfutures: Culture and Politics on the Information Superhighway, New York University Press, 1996. Susanne K. Schmidt and Raymund Werle, Coordinating Technology: Studies in the International Standardization of Telecommunications, Cambridge: MIT Press, 1997. Karen A. Schriver, Dynamics in Document Design: Creating Texts for Readers, Wiley, 1996. Werner Sichel and Donald L. Alexander, eds, Networks, Infrastructure, and the New Task for Regulation, Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 1996. Mark Stefik, Internet Dreams, Cambridge: MIT Press, 1996. John Tiffin and Lalita Rajasingham, In Search of the Virtual Class: Education in an Information Society, London: Routledge, 1995. Andrew B. Whinston, Dale O. Stahl, and Soon-Yong Choi, The Economics of Electronic Commerce, MacMillan, 1997. Rolf Wigand, Arnold Picot, and Ralf Reichwald, Information, Organization and Management: Expanding Markets and Corporate Boundaries, Wiley, 1997. Michael R. Williams, A History of Computing Technology, second edition, IEEE Computer Society, 1997. David B. Yoffie, ed, Competing in the Age of Digital Convergence, Boston: Harvard Business School Press, 1997. Mark W. Zacher and Brent A. Sutton, Governing Global Networks: International Regimes for Transportation and Communications, Cambridge University Press, 1996. end